Over
the period covered by the next financial perspective,
it is possible to face the challenges posed by the
necessary reforms of some of the most important
Community policies and those deriving from a first
wave of accessions without exceeding the existing own
resources ceiling (1.27% of GNP). As a result, there
are no technical or legal reasons which impose a
modification of the decision at the basis of the
financing arrangements. The current own resources
decision will remain in force as long as it is not
modified by a new one.
The
question of the opportunity of proposing a
modification of the current financing arrangements
rests therefore on an assessment of their current and
expected performance. This assessment will have to
take into account the fact that a modification of the
own resources decision would require unanimity among
the Member States and ratification by national
parliaments.
1.
The functioning of the system
As
demanded by Article 10 of the own resources decision,
the Commission will present in the course of 1998 a
full report on the functioning of the own resources
system covering also the mechanism used to reduce the
contribution of the United Kingdom and the
possibility to introduce a new own resource. It is,
however, already possible, even at this stage, to
draw some broad conclusions.
The
current arrangements have provided the Union with an
adequate amount of financial resources and look
likely to do so for the period covered by the next
financial perspective. The margin available under the
own resources ceiling has never been fully utilised.
This has been due to various factors such as
systematic underspending, e.g. in the agricultural
area, and delays in carrying out commitments, e.g. in
structural spending. Since 1997 the reduction in the
increase in expenditure, measured as a percentage of
GNP, has been the result of cautious budgetary
decisions, in line with the budgetary consolidation
efforts of the Member States,. These trends, combined
with the increases in the own resource ceiling for
the years 1997-99, are creating a margin which will
help to accommodate a first wave of accessions.
The
last modification of the own resources decision,
whose effect has started being felt from 1995
onwards, has made the system more
equitable by bringing national contributions more in
line with the shares in GNP. The weight of the VAT
resource, whose yield is poorly correlated with
contributive capacity, is being reduced. Whereas in
1992 the VAT resource still represented 61.6 %
of the total resources put at the disposal of the
Union, in 1996 this share was down to 51 % and
is expected to drop to about 33 % by 1999. The
increase in the relative share of the GNP
contribution, however, has been less rapid than
anticipated as actual Union spending (and
contributions) is increasing less than what is
allowed by the own resources ceiling and less than
what had been anticipated in 1992. While some
improvement in the "fairness" of the
financing system has already taken place, the largest
part is still to come.
The
share of the Community budget financed by the so
called "traditional own resources" (custom
duties and agricultural levies) has also continued to
decline. In 1992 these resources still represented
22 % of total receipts, but in 1999 they are
expected to drop below 15 %.
2.
The introduction of a new own resource?
The
trend described in the previous paragraph often
prompts the demand for the introduction of a new own
resource to increase the percentage of tax-based own
resources. The VAT and GNP contributions are
perceived by Member States as transfers from the
national exchequers and not as real own resources of
the Community.
However,
the introduction of new own resources still presents
technical and, above all, institutional obstacles.
One important consideration is that the fiscal
autonomy of the Union would not be significantly
enhanced by an increase in the share of financing
provided by tax-based own resources. As long as the
residual financing of the budget is covered by a
"complementary" resource activating
transfers from the national exchequers, any increase
in Community spending would still translate in a
corresponding increase in own resources payments. A
real modification would be brought about only by the
passage to a situation where the whole of the
Community budget would be financed by autonomous
fiscal resources. However, this would represent a
significant institutional development that would have
little chance of being countenanced by all Member
States in the present phase of the integration
process.
In
addition, the introduction of any new resource is
likely to make the system less equitable as the yield
pattern of the new resource by Member State is
unlikely to correspond to the GNP shares and require
the introduction of an equalisation mechanism that
would adjust national contributions to make them
correspond to the GNP shares. While this mechanism
would make the system more equitable, it would also
raise the question of whether it would not be more
cost-effective to switch to a system entirely based
on GNP contributions.
Indeed,
a strong case could be made for replacing the VAT
resource. Its weak link with contributive capacity
has already led to the decision to reduce its
importance. Furthermore, in the countries where the
harmonised base is capped, the resource is already
effectively a GNP resource since its base is a
conventional "50% of GNP". A good case
could also be made for replacing traditional own
resources with GNP contributions. As the importance
of traditional own resources for the financing of the
Community budget decreases, the balance between their
advantages and disadvantages as a source of Community
finance shifts towards the latter. In particular,
their collection and recovery procedures are very
complicated, exposed to fraud and very costly in
terms of controls. This would not mean that the Union
could ignore the effective collection of customs
duties by Member States since these duties constitute
an instrument of Union trade policy, but would modify
substantially the perspective of its involvement in
this complex area.
On
the whole, the considerations presented in this
section do not suggest the existence of a strong case
for a rapid modification of the present arrangements.
3.
Main trends to 2006
A
first wave of accessions will affect the budgetary
positions of all the present Member States, reducing
the positive balances of net beneficiaries and
increasing the negative ones of the others. The
applicant countries have levels of prosperity
significantly below those of the Union and will have
therefore a strong claim to substantial amounts of
Structural Fund payments. In addition, the experience
of the enlargement to Spain and Portugal suggests
that long transition periods for the "own
resources" payments of the applicant countries
might be introduced.
Future
expenditure flows in the Union will also be
influenced by the necessary reforms of the main
policies. The common agricultural policy will be
modified along the lines of the previous reform and
the changes will affect essentially the same
products. The new reform will therefore affect the
budgetary positions of the Member States along the
pattern of the previous one. However, its effects on
the budgetary positions might be smaller as income
losses will only be partially offset by increases in
direct aids.
tructural
Fund spending in the new Member States will be
financed through a combination of greater
concentration of spending in the present Member
States (which may supply about one third of the
amounts needed) and of use of the margins created by
economic growth (the other two thirds). However, the
regions which will remain classified as
"objective 1" and which experience high
rates of unemployment will benefit from higher per
capita transfers.
Internal
policies will focus more on some key themes such as
research and development efforts and the support of
the completion of the trans-European networks. This
concentration will be accompanied by stronger
emphasis on selection criteria such as excellency and
Community interest. This should lead to a more
balanced distribution of expenditure among Member
States.
Whereas
the future budgetary trends for the United Kingdom
are no more difficult to forecast than those for the
other Member States, a considerable amount of
uncertainty surrounds its future position in terms of
relative prosperity, which is one of the factors at
the base of the rebate granted to this country.
Producing a projection of the relative prosperity of
the United Kingdom to the year 2006 depends on
forecasting, over a period of nine years, the rates
of economic growth and of inflation of all Member
States and the relative trend of the pound sterling
if the United Kingdom decided not to join EMU. In a
Union of 15 members, it is likely that in 2006 the
relative prosperity of the United Kingdom would still
be below the average of the Union. The accession of
four or five of the applicant countries, however,
might change this tentative conclusion.
At
the time of the enlargement, it will be necessary to
adapt the definition of the expenditure on which the
calculation of the rebate is based to avoid an
unjustified increase in its amount due to purely
statistical changes. This is made necessary by the
fact that with enlargement some expenditure flows
directed to the new Member States, which are now
considered "external expenditure" and
therefore do not enter into the calculation, will be
replaced by payments under internal policies, which
enter into the calculation.
4.
The future financing system
National
contributions to the Union budget have become more
proportional to GNP shares, thus improving the degree
of fairness of the current financing system.
Community expenditure has been increasingly directed
at achieving cohesion goals, which has implied a
substantial amount of redistribution. Even if
relative positions have developed in line with what
had been expected at the time of the negotiation of
the present own resources decision, in some cases the
combination of these trends and of low returns from
agricultural expenditure has resulted in budgetary
positions which are perceived as excessive net
financial burdens.
The
next enlargement, which will take place during the
period covered by the next financial perspective,
will inevitably provoke a deterioration in the
budgetary positions of all the current Member States.
This cannot come as a surprise and should not give
rise to claims for compensation.
However,
over the same period, the maintenance of the current
financing arrangements and the effects of the reform
of the main Community policies are not expected to
lead to major changes in the relative budgetary
positions of the Member States.
The
uncertainties surrounding the future relative
prosperity situation of the United Kingdom,
however, lead the Commission to propose postponing a
re-examination of the rebate mechanism until
immediately after the first enlargement.
At
that moment, it will be possible to proceed to an
assessment of the situation on the basis of more
reliable data. If the relative prosperity of this
country were to be above the Unions average, it
would be appropriate to review the current
arrangements and to foresee a gradual reduction of
the current rebate.
The
review might be extended to the financing of the
budgetary rebate. If the data were to show that the
effects of the reform of the common agricultural
policy were significantly different from those
expected and that they were leading to unjustifiable
budgetary positions it might be conceivable to adjust
its financing key. A first step in this direction was
taken already in Fontainebleau when it was decided
that Germany would pay two thirds of the amount
resulting from the standard GNP key.
If
and when the Union were to require an increase in its
financial resources beyond the present 1.27% of GNP
ceiling, a more fundamental reform might be
considered. In such a case, it might become possible
to re-examine the whole structure of the system of
own resources. If, in addition, the budgetary
positions were to be significantly affected by the
increase in expenditure or by the reform of the
structure of financing, it could be appropriate to
envisage the introduction of a generalised system of
corrections, which would also address the problems of
the United Kingdom, aimed at smoothing further
deteriorations of the largest budgetary imbalances.
|